There is a strong consensus today about the importance of elementary education in Indian public policy. It is hard to imagine how productivity and income growth can come about for the 55% of India which is illiterate. Going beyond economics, there are significant returns to education as far as social development and politics are concerned. It is hard to imagine how social progress can be obtained with 55% illiteracy. There is little doubt that the persistent importance of religion and caste in India is linked to ignorance, and illiteracy is clearly the most extreme form of ignorance.
From this perspective, one common
theme that has emerged is that while the liberalisation of 1990s has involved
taking the State out of myriad aspects of the Indian economy, there remains a
major role for the State in elementary education. Indeed, the withdrawal of the
State from other areas should help free up resources for education and health.
Why is elementary education special?
Why should the State spend on elementary education? A common reason that is
supplied is that poor people are too backward to invest in education by
themselves; hence the only way to ensure that their children grow up educated
is through large government interventions. This argument is highly suspect.
Some evidence about this question is presented later in this article.
The second, and more defensible
rationale for public expenditures for elementary education is based upon
"externalities" of education. Each educated person generates myriad
benefits for all those around him, and he, individually, cannot capture
the full benefits of his education that accrue to society. Hence
individuals have an incentive to underinvest in education. This justifies an
intervention by the State, which would spend on education, generate these
positive benefits, and take away part (but not all) of these benefits as taxes.
These arguments justify public
expenditures on elementary education, and these expenditures have grown
enormously in the 1990s. Yet, educational outcomes have not improved
sharply. Illiteracy is still substantially with us -- from 60% in 1990 to 50%
in 2000 AD. Children fail to enroll in schools in enormous numbers, and the
drop--out rate is very high amongst those that do.
We must shift focus from the inputs,
such as public expenses on education or the number of schools, to outputs,
which are educational outcomes. If elementary education is important,
then we should focus upon outcomes, measured in terms of literacy rates,
and school enrollment rates at age 7 and 15. If the educational system is badly
functioning, then adding money at the input is an inefficient way to improve
outcomes.
India's educational outcomes are a
spectacular failure when compared with dozens of countries which achieved
complete literacy in a generation after 1945. Part of this problem is rooted in
low public expenditure upon education in India. But an even more important
problem lies in the inefficient Sate--dominated education system.
The public sector is a highly
inefficient producer of educational services (just as it is inefficient in
producing watches, or banking services, or telecom services). In keeping with
the spirit of liberalisation, we should try to obtain better educational
services by using competition in the private sector.
Writing in the book Agenda for
Change recently produced by the Rajiv Gandhi Institute for Contemporary
Studies, Parth J. Shah has an elegant and simple idea which goes to the heart
of this problem. At present, the government spends roughly Rs.3000 per year per
child in primary school. This money is spent upon the (inefficient) production
of educational services by the public sector. Instead, a totally different
approach should be used. Government should completely get out of the production
of educational services; all schools should be run by the private sector and
charge fees. Parents should be provided with coupons worth Rs.3000 per child
per year which they pay to the school of their choice. Coupon
distribution is efficiently implemented, for example, by giving parents 12
coupons when a child is born.
The essential desirable features
here are choice by consumers, and competition in the private sector. The
private sector would work to run profit--making schools, charging fees of
Rs.3000/year and above. Parents would be able to select between multiple
competing schools. Some schools would offer teaching at the floor price of
Rs.3000/year, other schools would charge higher fees where parents supplement
the government subsidy by their own funds.
In this proposal, parents are
empowered. If a school produces a poor education, parents would move their
children to a competing school. This will be the most important ground--level
check upon the quality of educational services and hence educational outcomes.
Parth Shah describes a remarkable idea that has been used in Kerala: the
government reimburses the transportation costs faced by children in
commuting to school. This measure increases the choices available to parents,
and avoids the problem of a local monopoly.
This proposal is criticised on the
grounds that poor people are so ignorant that they will give their vouchers to
scamsters who will make off with Rs.3000 and not supply any education. This
assumes that poor people are uninterested in the education of their children.
Parth Shah offers powerful evidence which shows that the poorest quintile of
India -- households which earn under Rs.3000 per capita per year -- spends
between 10% to 36% of their family income upon education of their children.
This is in a regime where primary education is supposed to be free -- these
poorest of the poor choose to supplement the low--quality educational
services, that the government supplies them, with additional services which
they buy. This is sharp evidence about the extent to which the poor of India
care about the education of their children.
In this sense, the evidence about
low enrollment rates and high dropout rates is quite likely to be related to
the poor quality of the education which public sector schools provide. If
parents were given better schools that their children could attend, it is very
likely that enrollment rates would rise.
Private sector schools, competing
for enrollment, would think innovatively in trying to produce better educational
services. One simple example which Parth Shah offers is that of the timings
which schools use. The timings are presently chosen in a way which is
convenient for government employees. In rural areas, a schedule such as 2 PM to
8 PM would be highly convenient, since it allows children to work on farms in
the morning and then attend school. When educational services are produced by
the public sector, as they are at present, there will be no effort at trying to
think about the customer and improving the quality of service from his
perspective. If all parents were armed with coupons worth Rs.3,000, private
sector production of educational services will blossom in quality and customer
orientation. This will lead to better education, and better educational
outcomes.
In summary, there is a strong case
for the State to care about education, but we must shift focus from inputs,
such as the money spent upon education, to outputs, which are
educational outcomes. Educational outcomes in India can be dramatically
improved, without enlarged public expenditure upon education, by the simple
idea of putting parents in complete control of the Rs.3000 per child per year
that we currently spend in the country.
No comments:
Post a Comment